Medical Spending and Savings of Aging Households

07/09/2020
Featured in print Reporter
By Mariacristina De Nardi

Members of older households face the prospect of living longer than expected and incurring large medical expenses. My research on old age aims at better quantifying these risks, studying their implications for savings, consumption, and welfare, and evaluating the extent to which current government programs insure older people.

The first part of my research on these topics focuses on elderly singles, who comprise about 50 percent of people aged 70 or older. The second part extends the analysis to include elderly couples. The third focuses on the effect of health risk on older households’ resources and the utility that they derive from consumption in various states of health, considering both couples and singles.

Risk, Savings, and Insurance among Singles

Eric French, John Bailey Jones, and I study the population of retired single people.1 We use high-quality data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) to construct a rich model of out-of-pocket medical spending and use an estimated structural model to assess its importance for retirement savings. We uncover several novel findings.

denardi figure
Figure 1

First, average out-of-pocket medical expenses rise rapidly with age and permanent income, especially after age 90 [Figure 1].

Second, older people with high permanent income hold more wealth and spend it more slowly. Figure 2 displays the median assets of surviving individuals, conditional on birth cohort and permanent-income quintile. It shows that singles with high permanent income (set of top lines) hold significant amounts of wealth well into their 90s, that those with the lowest permanent income never save much (bottom lines, often flush against the horizontal axis), and that those in the middle draw down their assets at a moderate rate (intermediate set of lines). Thus, even at older ages, richer people save more, a finding first documented by Karen Dynan, Jonathan Skinner, and Stephen Zeldes for the whole life cycle.2

Third, longevity increases with income and varies greatly across observable characteristics.  At age 70, people in the top permanent-income quintile typically live three and a half years longer than those in the bottom quintile.  In addition, we find that while a 70-year-old man in poor health in the bottom income quintile is estimated to live only six more years, a 70-year-old woman in good health and in the top income quintile can be expected to live 17 more years.3

These differences in mortality are important not only to understand older individuals’ saving behavior, but to properly measure savings themselves. Because male, unhealthy, low-income people die younger, at older ages our sample is increasingly composed of women, people with high lifetime earnings, and those who had good health at younger ages. Failing to account for this mortality bias would lead us to understate asset draw-down by over 50 percent. To account for this, we explicitly model mortality bias in our structural model, where people who are rich, healthy, and female have higher rates of survival.

Fourth, we use an estimated structural model to evaluate how medical expenditures affect the saving of elderly singles. Our model predicts that, absent all out-of-pocket medical expenses, the median assets of those in the highest permanent-income quintile would fall by 64 percent between the ages of 74 and 84, instead of the 23 percent that we observe. Thus, out-of-pocket medical expenses are an important reason why high-permanent-income people hold large savings later in life. Out-of-pocket medical expenses that rise very rapidly with age and income provide the elderly with a strong incentive to save, and medical expenses that rise with permanent income encourage the rich to be more frugal.

denardi figure2
Figure 2

We also use our structural model to show that the government-provided consumption floor — mainly Supplemental Security Income (SSI) and Medicaid — affects saving decisions at all levels of income. This is not surprising, given the size of our estimated medical needs for the old and income-rich; even wealthy households can be financially decimated by medical needs in very old age.

In subsequent work, French, Jones, and I focus on the role of Medicaid in insuring against old-age risks and determining savings.4 Although Medicare assists the great majority of people over 65, its beneficiaries are still responsible for insurance premia and copays. Furthermore, Medicare does not cover extended nursing home stays. These expenses are covered out of pocket or, for those with low income and assets or those made financially destitute by catastrophic medical spending, by Medicaid.

We start by documenting new facts on Medicaid recipiency after age 70. We use HRS data to show that, while the Medicaid recipiency rate in the bottom permanent-income quintile is around 70 percent throughout retirement, the recipiency rate of higher permanent-income retirees is initially very low but increases with age, reaching 20 percent for the top quintile by age 95. Thus, even high permanent-income people become Medicaid recipients if they live long enough and develop expensive medical conditions. We use the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey to show another important fact; namely, that conditional on receiving Medicaid transfers, high-income people receive larger transfers than low-income people.

We then develop and estimate a life-cycle model of consumption and medical spending. Individuals face uncertainty about their health, life span, and medical needs, including nursing home stays. The model accounts for Medicare, SSI, and Medicaid. Consistent with program rules, we model two pathways to Medicaid: one for the lifelong poor and one for people impoverished by large medical expenses.

The model shows that the current Medicaid system provides different kinds of insurance to households with different resources. Households in the lower permanent-income quintiles are much more likely to receive Medicaid transfers, but the transfers that they receive are on average relatively small. Households in the higher permanent-income quintiles are much less likely to receive any Medicaid transfers, but when they do, these transfers are large and correspond to severe and expensive medical conditions. Medicaid is thus effective for the poorest, but also offers valuable insurance to the rich against catastrophic medical conditions, which are the most difficult to insure through saving and in the private market.

Our estimates imply that with moderate risk aversion and realistic lifetime and medical needs risk, the value that most retirees place on Medicaid insurance exceeds the actuarial value of their expected payments. On the other hand, we find that a Medicaid expansion would be valued by most retirees at less than its cost. These comparisons suggest that there would be limited demand for expanding the current Medicaid program.

Bequests, Expense Risks, and Savings

Our previous work has focused on elderly singles. Much less is known about the reasons couples save. Is it to make sure that the surviving spouse can live comfortably after one dies? To leave bequests to heirs other than the surviving spouse? To pay for future medical expenses? And how do these saving motives interact?

Rory McGee, Rachel Rodgers, French, Jones, and I collect evidence on these issues by documenting how assets change when a household member dies.5 Using a matching estimator, we find that when the last person in a household dies, his or her assets fall, relative to survivors, by about $20,000. When one member of a couple dies, household assets fall, relative to intact couples, by around $90,000. End-of-life expenses, mostly medical, are sufficient to explain the asset declines measured for singles, but fall short of explaining the declines observed for couples. Bequests from dying spouses to non-spousal heirs such as children are more than sufficient to explain the remainder.

In ongoing work, French, Jones, McGee, and I extend our modeling of old age risks and saving behavior to include couples.6 We use HRS data to document that the savings of singles stay roughly constant or fall during retirement, but the savings of couples stay constant or increase until one of the spouses dies. In addition, we find that savings drop sharply leading up to the death of each spouse and, by the time the second spouse dies, a large fraction of the wealth of the couple has vanished. These facts are consistent with the findings of James Poterba, Steven Venti, and David Wise.7

We then develop and estimate a structural model in which people face longevity, health, and medical expense risks, and potentially care about their surviving spouse and other heirs. Our results for singles reinforce earlier findings: most singles mainly save to self-insure against future medical expenses.

Our preliminary results for couples uncover several new findings.

First, the desire to leave assets to the surviving spouse is an important reason why couples at all permanent income levels hold assets at very advanced ages. If couples did not care about the welfare of their surviving spouse, at age 94 the median assets of couples in the top permanent-income tercile would be 30 percent lower, the median assets of couples in the middle-income tercile would be 50 percent lower, and the median assets of couples in the lowest permanent-income tercile would be 75 percent lower.

Second, the desire to leave bequests to heirs other than one’s spouse has large effects on the savings of couples with high permanent income but almost no effects on the savings of couples at the low and middle permanent-income levels. At age 94, couples in the highest permanent-income tercile would hold 20 percent fewer assets if they did not have a bequest motive toward non-spousal heirs.

Third, while the savings of both couples and singles in the lowest and middle permanent-income terciles are mostly driven by medical expenses, the interaction of medical expenses, including those borne by the surviving spouse after a death, and bequest motives has large effects on the savings of couples with higher permanent income. For instance, the median assets of couples in the top permanent-income tercile would be about 90 percent lower if they did not face medical expenses and had no desire to leave a bequest, but the changes for those in lower permanent-income terciles would be much smaller.

Health Risk, Resources, and Utility from Consumption

Importantly, my previously discussed research either assumes that health has no effect on the utility that one derives from non-medical consumption or fails to identify its effect. Richard Blundell, Margherita Borella, Jeanne Commault, and I use the HRS and the Consumption and Activities Mail Survey to study whether, in old age, consumption fluctuates because of shocks to available resources, or because health shocks affect the marginal utility that a household derives from consumption.8 The effects of health on available resources have also been studied by Edward Morrison, Arpit Gupta, Lenora Olson, Lawrence Cook, and Heather Keenan; by Poterba, Venti, and Wise; and by Carlos Dobkin, Amy Finkelstein, Raymond Kluender, and Matthew Notowidigdo.9

The main findings are the following: first, after age 65, even temporary changes in income and health are associated with changes in consumption. A 10 percent temporary drop in income comes with a 1 percent drop in nondurable consumption, and a one-standard-deviation temporary drop in health is associated with a 2 percent drop in nondurable consumption. Thus, temporary ill health is associated with drops in consumption.

Second, most of the effect of temporary changes in health comes from the change in marginal utility from consumption. More specifically, a temporary health shock that reduces the health index by one standard deviation reduces nondurable consumption by 2.8 percent.  About 0.3 percent of this decline is the result of the change in resources, while the rest is the result of a health-induced shift in the marginal utility generated by consumption.

Third, we show that after a health shock, richer households only adjust their consumption of luxury goods, mostly because the marginal utility from consuming them declines. Poorer households also experience a hit in resources, but then adjust their consumption of both necessary and luxury goods.

Our findings inform the extent to which existing government programs help insure against the large risks that households face during old age, as well as the reasons households save. They therefore illustrate how policy reforms would affect both their savings and their welfare.

Endnotes

1.

Differential Mortality, Uncertain Medical Expenses, and the Saving of Elderly Singles,” De Nardi M, French E, Jones JB. NBER Working Paper 12554, October 2006. Published as “Why Do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses,” Journal of Political Economy 118(1), February 2010, pp. 39–75.
 

2.

Do the Rich Save More?” Dynan KE, Skinner J, Zeldes SP. NBER Working Paper 7906, September 2000, and the Journal of Political Economy 112(2), April 2004, pp. 397–444.
 

3.

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings,” De Nardi M, French E, Jones JB. NBER Working Paper 14653, January 2009, and the American Economic Review 99(2), May 2009, pp. 39–75.
 

4.

Medicaid Insurance in Old Age,” De Nardi M, French E, Jones JB. NBER Working Paper 19151, June 2013, revised December 2015, and the American Economic Review 106(11), November 2016, pp. 3480–3520.
 

5.

Medical Spending, Bequests, and Asset Dynamics around the Time of Death,” Jones JB, De Nardi M, French E, McGee R, Rodgers R. NBER Working Paper 26879, March 2020.
 

6.

Couples’ and Singles’ Savings after Retirement,” De Nardi M, French E, Jones JB, McGee R. Mimeo.
 

7.

The Composition and Drawdown of Wealth in Retirement,” Poterba J, Venti SF, Wise DA. NBER Working Paper 17536, October 2011, and the Journal of Economic Perspectives 25(4), Fall 2011, pp. 95–118.
 

8.

Why Does Consumption Fluctuate in Old Age and How Should the Government Insure It?” Blundell R, Borella M, Commault J, De Nardi M. NBER Working Paper 27348, June 2020.
 

9.

Health and Financial Fragility: Evidence from Car Crashes and Consumer Bankruptcy,” Morrison ER, Gupta A, Olson L, Cook L, Keenan H. University of Chicago Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics research paper, 665, November 2013; “Longitudinal Determinants of End-of-Life Wealth Inequality,” Poterba J, Venti SF, Wise DA. NBER Working Paper 23839, September 2017, revised May 2018, and Journal of Public Economics 162, June 2018, pp. 78–88; “The Economic Consequences of Hospital Admission,” Dobkin C, Finkelstein A, Kluender R, Notowidigdo MJ. NBER Working Paper 22288, May 2016, revised August 2016, and American Economic Review 108(2), February 2018, pp. 308–352.